首頁>> >> 经济商企>> 亞當·斯密 Adam Smith   英國 United Kingdom   漢諾威王朝   (1723年六月5日1790年七月17日)
國民財富的性質和原因的研究 An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
  國民財富的性質和原因的研究
   
  AN INQUIRY INTO THE NATURE AND CAUSES OF THE WEALTH ON NATIONS
   
  
  作者:亞當·斯密(Adam Smith,LL.D)
  
  郭大力 王亞南 譯
  
  序論及全書設計
  ◎第一篇 論勞動生産力增進的原因並論勞動生産物自然而然地分配給各階級人民的順序
  第一章 論分工
  第二章 論分工的原由
  第三章 論分工受市場範圍的限製
  第四章 論貨幣的起源及其效用
  第五章 論商品的真實價格與名義價格或其勞動價格與貨幣價格
  第六章 論商品價格的組成部分
  第七章 論商品的自然價格與市場價格
  第八章 論勞動工資
  第九章 論資本利潤
  第十章 論工資與利潤隨勞動與資本用途的不同而不同
  第十一章 論地租
  ◎第二篇 論資財的性質及其蓄積和用途
  序論
  第一章 論資財的劃分
  第二章 論作為社會總資財的一部門或作為維持國民資本的費用的貨幣
  第三章 論資本積纍並論生産性和非生産性勞動
  第四章 論貸出取息的資財
  第五章 論資本的各種用途
  ◎第三篇 論不同國傢中財富的不同發展
  第一章 論財富的自然的發展
  第二章 論羅馬帝國崩潰後農業在歐洲舊狀態下所受到的阻抑
  第三章 論羅馬帝國崩潰後都市的勃興與進步
  第四章 都市商業對農村改良的貢獻
  ◎第四篇 論政治經濟學體係
  序論
  第一章 商業主義或重商主義的原理
  第二章 論限製從外國輸入國內能生産的貨物
  第三章 論對其貿易的差額被認為不利於我國的那些國傢的各種貨物的輸入所加的異常限製
  第四章 論退稅
  第五章 論奬勵金
  第六章 論通商條約
  第七章 論殖民地
  第八章 關於重商主義的結論
  第九章 論重農主義即政治經濟學中把土地生産物看作各國收入及財富的唯一
  ◎第五篇 論君主或國傢的收入
  第一章 論君主或國傢的費用
  第二章 論一般收入或公共收入的源泉
  第三章 論公債


  An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (generally referred to by the short title The Wealth of Nations) is the Magnum Opus of the Scottish economist and moral philosopher Adam Smith. First published in 1776, it is a reflection on economics at the beginning of the Industrial Revolution and argues that free market economies are more productive and beneficial to their societies. The book, written for the educated, is considered to be the foundation of modern economic theory.
  
  History
  
  The Wealth of Nations was first published on March 9, 1776, during the British Agricultural Revolution. It influenced not only authors and economists, but governments and organizations. For example, Alexander Hamilton was influenced in part by The Wealth of Nations to write his Report on Manufactures, in which he argued against many of Smith's policies. Interestingly, Hamilton based much of this report on the ideas of Jean-Baptiste Colbert, and it was, in part, to Colbert's ideas that Smith responded to with The Wealth of Nations.
  
  Many other authors were influenced by the book and used it as a starting point in their own work, including Jean-Baptiste Say, David Ricardo, Thomas Malthus and, later, Karl Marx and Ludwig von Mises. The Russian national poet Aleksandr Pushkin refers to The Wealth of Nations in his 1833 verse-novel Eugene Onegin.
  
  Irrespective of historical influence, however, The Wealth of Nations represented a clear leap forward in the field of economics, similar to Sir Isaac Newton's Principia Mathematica for physics, Antoine Lavoisier's Traité Élémentaire de Chimie for chemistry, or Charles Darwin's On the Origin of Species for biology.
  
   Publishing history
  
  Five editions of The Wealth of Nations were published during Smith's lifetime: in 1776, 1778, 1784, 1786, and 1789. Numerous editions appeared after Smith's death in 1790. To better understand the evolution of the work under Smith's hand, a team led by Edwin Cannan collated the first five editions. The differences were published along with an edited sixth edition in 1904. They found minor but numerous differences (including the addition of many footnotes) between the first and the second editions, both of which were published in two volumes. The differences between the second and third editions, however, are major: In 1784, Smith annexed these first two editions with the publication of Additions and Corrections to the First and Second Editions of Dr. Adam Smith’s Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, and he also had published the now three volume third edition of the Wealth of Nations, which incorporated Additions and Corrections and, for the first time, an index. Among other things, the Additions and Corrections included entirely new sections. The fourth edition published in 1786 had only slight differences with the third edition, and Smith himself says in the Advertisement at the beginning of the book, "I have made no alterations of any kind." Finally, Cannan notes only trivial differences between the fourth and fifth editions — a set of misprints being removed from the fourth and a different set of misprints being introduced.
  
   Anachronisms and terminology
  
  Some commentary[who?] on the work suffers from anachronism - imposition of modern context and political contests on a two hundred and fifty year old work.
  
  The book is written in the English of the late 18th century, so there are some points to consider:
  
   * The term economics was not yet in use.
   * The term capitalism was not yet in use. Smith talks about a "system of perfect liberty" or "system of natural liberty".
   * Feudalism was still dominant in parts of Europe.
   * The term corporation, as in feudal corporations, referred to a body that regulated and, in Smith's portrayal, limited participation in a skilled trade.
  
  
   Synopsi
   This article's plot summary may be too long or overly detailed. Please help improve it by removing unnecessary details and making it more concise. (October 2009)
  
   Book I: Of the Causes of Improvement...
  
  Of the Division of Labour: Smith states that "the greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the greater part of the skill, dexterity, and judgement with which it is anywhere directed, or applied, seem to have been the effects of the division of labour." To illustrate this, he describes the extensive division of labour within the "trifling" industry of pin manufacture, along with the astounding resultant productivity, and labourers' dexterity; then levers this as an introductory microcosm of the greater, yet less obvious division of labour in the broader economy. The advantages of this division were likely the driving force behind diversification of the trades and industry, and this diversification was greatest for nations with more industry and improvement. Agriculture is differentiated from industry for its comparative lack of division of labour, and the attendant lack of improved productivity; hence, while poor nations could not compete with rich nations in manufactures, they could compete in agriculture.
  
  Smith lists three causes, arising from division, of improved productivity:
  
   * The labourer's dexterity - due to specializing, year-round, in a specific task
   * Time not wasted passing from one task to the next—as in agriculture—as well as the more consistent and focused effort when working in just one area
   * The machines and tools that have evolved in conjunction with increasingly specialized labour
  
  Many "natural" differences between men are according to Adam Smith only the results of the division of labour:
  
   "The difference of natural talents in different men is, in reality, much less than we are aware of; and the very different genius which appears to distinguish men of different professions, when grown up to maturity, is not upon many occasions so much the cause, as the effect of the division of labour. The difference between the most dissimilar characters, between a philosopher seems to arise not so much from nature, as from habit, custom, and education."
  
  Of the Principle which gives Occasion to the Division of Labour: Chapter 2 illustrates the growth in division of labour. Smith hypothesizes that early societies benefited from specialization in a natural and spontaneous way - that one person may focus on hunting while another concentrates on bow-making.
  
  That the Division of Labour is Limited by the Extent of the Market: Chapter 3 deals with limitations on division of labour. Smith illustrates with real world examples of how the extent of market determines the level of division of labour and the resulting productivity improvements; it is the extent of the market that determines the degree to which the division of labour can proceed – the productivity gains of a limited market are limited. On the other hand, as under competitive conditions a deepening of the division of labour lowers prices and thereby increases sales, the division of labour leads to an extended market that permits another deepening of the division of labour. This dynamic process creates the “Wealth of Nations.” It allowed England to undersell all its competitors and become the workshop of the world. Monopolies and patents may block this process, which depends on decreasing prices.
  
  Of the Origin and Use of Money: When money was first invented, it was not well regulated, which made agriculture and trade in commodities very difficult between individual owners.
  
  Of the Real and Nominal Price of Commodities, or of their Price in Labour, and their Price in Money: In the first two passages Smith gives two conflicting definitions of the relative value of a commodity. Ricardo responded to one of Smith's inconsistencies in the Preface of his "Principles":
  
   "The writer, in combating received opinions, has found it necessary to advert more particularly to those passages in the writings of Adam Smith from which he sees reason to differ; but he hopes it will not, on that account, be suspected that he does not, in common with all those who acknowledge the importance of the science of Political Economy, participate in the admiration which the profound work of this celebrated author so justly excites."
  
  Adam Smith defines the value of commodities by the labour embedded and also by the labour a good commands. Ricardo agrees with the first definition:
  
  “The real price of every thing,” says Adam Smith, “What every thing really costs to the man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. What every thing is really worth to the man who has acquired it, and who wants to dispose of it, or exchange it for something else, is the toil and trouble which it can save to himself, and which it can impose upon other people. That this is really the foundation of the exchangeable value of all things, excepting those which cannot be increased by human industry, is a doctrine of the utmost importance in political economy“.
  
  For Ricardo, the value of reproducible commodities and services reflects the relative difficulties of production counted in labour units: direct labour plus the dated labour of the past embedded in inputs (capital) and corrected by interests. This differs from Smith’s second definition of value:
  
   "The value of any commodity … is equal to the quantity of labour which it enables him to purchase or command. Labour, therefore, is the real measure of the exchangeable value of all commodities."
  
  Ricardo disagrees:
  
   "Adam Smith, who so accurately defined the original source of exchangeable value … speaks of things being more or less valuable, in proportion as they will exchange for more or less of this standard measure. … [N]ot the quantity of labour bestowed on the production of any object, but the quantity which it can command in the market: as if these were two equivalent expressions…"
  
  Smith’s second definition pleases neoclassical economists, who determine value by the utility that a commodity provides a person rather than cost of production as do classical economists.
  
  Of the Component Parts of the Price of Commodities: Smith argues that the price of any product reflects wages, rent of land and "...profit of stock," which compensates the capitalist for risking his resources.
  
  Of the Natural and Market Price of Commodities:
  
   "When the quantity of any commodity which is brought to market falls short of the effectual demand, all those who are willing to pay... cannot be supplied with the quantity which they want... Some of them will be willing to give more. A competition will begin among them, and the market price will rise... When the quantity brought to market exceeds the effectual demand, it cannot be all sold to those who are willing to pay the whole value of the rent, wages and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it thither... The market price will sink..."
  
  To paraphrase Smith, and the first part of this Chapter, when demand exceeds supply, the price goes up. When the supply exceeds demand, the price goes down.
  
  He then goes on to comment on the different avenues that people can take to generate a larger profit than normal. Some of those include: finding a commodity that few others have that allows for a high profit, and being able to keep that secret; Finding a way to produce a unique commodity (The dyer who discovers a unique dye). He also states that the former usually has a short lifespan of high profitability, and the latter has a longer. He also notes that a monopoly is essentially the same as the dyers trade secret, and can thus lead to high profitability for a long time by keeping the supply below the effectual demand.
  
   "A monopoly granted either to an individual or to a trading company has the same effect as a secret in trade or manufactures. The monopolists, by keeping the market constantly understocked, by never fully supplying the effectual demand, sell their commodities much above the natural price, and raise their emoluments, whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly above their natural rate. The price of monopoly is upon every occasion the highest which can be got. The natural price, or the price of free competition, on the contrary, is the lowest which can be taken, not upon every occasion, indeed, but for any considerable time together. The one is upon every occasion the highest which can be squeezed out of the buyers, or which, it is supposed, they will consent to give: the other is the lowest which the sellers can commonly afford to take, and at the same time continue their business."
  
  Of the Wages of Labour: In this section, Smith describes how the wages of labour are dictated primarily by the competition among labourers and masters. When labourers bid against one another for limited opportunities for employment, the wages of labour collectively fall, whereas when employers compete against one another for limited supplies of labour, the wages of labour collectively rise. However, this process of competition is often circumvented by combinations among labourers and among masters. When labourers combine and no longer bid against one another, their wages rise, whereas when masters combine, wages fall. In Smith's day, it should be noted, organized labour was dealt with very harshly by the law.
  
  Smith himself wrote about the "severity" of such laws against worker actions, and made a point to contrast the "clamour" of the "masters" against workers associations, while associations and collusions of the masters "are never heard by the people" though such actions are "always" and "everywhere" taking place:
  
   "We rarely hear, it has been said, of the combinations of masters, though frequently of those of workmen. But whoever imagines, upon this account, that masters rarely combine, is as ignorant of the world as of the subject. Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform, combination, not to raise the wages of labour above their actual rate...Masters, too, sometimes enter into particular combinations to sink the wages of labour even below this rate. These are always conducted with the utmost silence and secrecy till the moment of execution; and when the workmen yield, as they sometimes do without resistance, though severely felt by them, they are never heard of by other people" In contrast, when workers combine, "the masters..never cease to call aloud for the assistance of the civil magistrate, and the rigorous execution of those laws which have been enacted with so much severity against the combination of servants, labourers, and journeymen."
  
  In societies where the amount of labour exceeds the amount of revenue available for waged labour, competition among workers is greater than the competition among employers, and wages fall. Inversely, where revenue is abundant, labour wages rise. Smith argues that, therefore, labour wages only rise as a result of greater revenue disposed to pay for labour. Smith thought labour the same as any other commodity in this respect:
  
   "the demand for men, like that for any other commodity, necessarily regulates the production of men; quickens it when it goes on too slowly, and stops it when it advances too fast. It is this demand which regulates and determines the state of propagation in all the different countries of the world, in North America, in Europe, and in China; which renders it rapidly progressive in the first, slow and gradual in the second, and altogether stationary in the last."
  
  However, the amount of revenue must increase constantly in proportion to the amount of labour for wages to remain high. Smith illustrates this by juxtaposing England with the North American colonies. In England, there is more revenue than in the colonies, but wages are lower, because more workers flock to new employment opportunities caused by the large amount of revenue— so workers eventually compete against each other as much as they did before. By contrast, as capital continues to flow to the colonial economies at least at the same rate that population increases to "fill out" this excess capital, wages there stay higher than in England.
  
  Smith was highly concerned about the problems of poverty. He writes,
  
   "poverty, though it does not prevent the generation, is extremely unfavourable to the rearing of children... It is not uncommon... in the Highlands of Scotland for a mother who has borne twenty children not to have two alive... In some places one half the children born die before they are four years of age; in many places before they are seven; and in almost all places before they are nine or ten. This great mortality, however, will every where be found chiefly among the children of the common people, who cannot afford to tend them with the same care as those of better station."
  
  The only way to determine whether a man is rich or poor is to examine the amount of labour he can afford to purchase. "Labour is the real exchange for commodities".
  
  Smith also describes the relation of cheap years and the production of manufactures versus the production in dear years. He argues that while some examples such as the linen production in France shows a correlation, another example in Scotland shows the opposite. He concludes that there are too many variables to make any statement about this.
  
  Of the Profits of Stock: In this chapter, Smith uses interest rates as an indicator of the profits of stock. This is because interest can only be paid with the profits of stock, and so creditors will be able to raise rates in proportion to the increase or decrease of the profits of their debtors.
  
  Smith argues that the profits of stock are inversely proportional to the wages of labor, because as more money is spent compensating labor, there is less remaining for personal profit. It follows that, in societies where competition among laborers is greatest relative to competition among employers, profits will be much higher. Smith illustrates this by comparing interest rates in England and Scotland. In England, government laws against usury had kept maximum interest rates very low, but even the maximum rate was believed to be higher than the rate at which money was usually loaned. In Scotland, however, interest rates are much higher. This is the result of a greater proportion of capitalists in England, which offsets some competition among laborers and raises wages.
  
  However, Smith notes that, curiously, interest rates in the colonies are also remarkably high (recall that, in the previous chapter, Smith described how wages in the colonies are higher than in England). Smith attributes this to the fact that, when an empire takes control of a colony, prices for a huge abundance of land and resources are extremely cheap. This allows capitalists to increase his profit, but simultaneously draws many capitalists to the colonies, increasing the wages of labor. As this is done, however, the profits of stock in the mother country rise (or at least cease to fall), as much of it has already flocked offshore.
  
  Of Wages and Profit in the Different Employments of Labour and Stock: Smith repeatedly attacks groups of politically aligned individuals who attempt to use their collective influence to manipulate the government into doing their bidding. At the time, these were referred to as "factions," but are now more commonly called "special interests," a term that can comprise international bankers, corporate conglomerations, outright oligopolies, trade unions and other groups. Indeed, Smith had a particular distrust of the tradesman class. He felt that the members of this class, especially acting together within the guilds they want to form, could constitute a power block and manipulate the state into regulating for special interests against the general interest:
  
   "People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to do nothing to facilitate such assemblies; much less to render them necessary."
  
  Smith also argues against government subsidies of certain trades, because this will draw many more people to the trade than what would otherwise be normal, collectively lowering their wages.
  
  Chapter 10, part ii, motivates an understanding of the idea of feudalism.
  
  Of the Rent of the Land: Rent, considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally the highest the tenant can afford in the actual circumstances of the land. In adjusting lease terms, the landlord endeavours to leave him no greater share of the produce than what is sufficient to keep up the stock from which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and purchases and maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry, together with the ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood. This is evidently the smallest share with which the tenant can content himself without being a loser, and the landlord seldom means to leave him any more. Whatever part of the produce, or, what is the same thing, whatever part of its price, is over and above this share, he naturally endeavours to reserve to himself as the rent of his land, which is evidently the highest the tenant can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of the land. Sometimes, indeed, the liberality, more frequently the ignorance, of the landlord, makes him accept of somewhat less than this portion; and sometimes too, though more rarely, the ignorance of the tenant makes him undertake to pay somewhat more, or to content himself with somewhat less, than the ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood. This portion, however, may still be considered as the natural rent of land, or the rent for which it is naturally meant that land should for the most part be let.
  
   Book II: Of the Nature, Accumulation, and Employment of Stock
  
  Of the Division of Stock:
  
   "When the stock which a man possesses is no more than sufficient to maintain him for a few days or a few weeks, he seldom thinks of deriving any revenue from it. He consumes it as sparingly as he can, and endeavours by his labour to acquire something which may supply its place before it be consumed altogether. His revenue is, in this case, derived from his labour only. This is the state of the greater part of the labouring poor in all countries."
  
  II.1.1
  
   "But when he possesses stock sufficient to maintain him for months or years, he naturally endeavours to derive a revenue from the greater part of it; reserving only so much for his immediate consumption as may maintain him till this revenue begins to come in. His whole stock, therefore, is distinguished into two parts. That part which, he expects, is to afford him this revenue, is called his capital."
  
  Of Money Considered as a particular Branch of the General Stock of the Society...:
  
   "From references of the first book, that the price of the greater part of commodities resolves itself into three parts, of which one pays the wages of the labour, another the profits of the stock, and a third the rent of the land which had been employed in producing and bringing them to market: that there are, indeed, some commodities of which the price is made up of two of those parts only, the wages of labour, and the profits of stock: and a very few in which it consists altogether in one, the wages of labour: but that the price of every commodity necessarily resolves itself into some one, or other, or all of these three parts; every part of it which goes neither to rent nor to wages, being necessarily profit to somebody."
  
  Of the Accumulation of Capital, or of Productive and Unproductive Labour:
  
   "One sort of labour adds to the value of the subject upon which it is bestowed: there is another which has no such effect. The former, as it produces a value, may be called productive; the latter, unproductive labour. Thus the labour of a manufacturer adds, generally, to the value of the materials which he works upon, that of his own maintenance, and of his master's profit. The labour of a menial servant, on the contrary, adds to the value of nothing."
  
  Of Stock Lent at Interest:
  
   "The stock which is lent at interest is always considered as a capital by the lender. He expects that in due time it is to be restored to him, and that in the meantime the borrower is to pay him a certain annual rent for the use of it. The borrower may use it either as a capital, or as a stock reserved for immediate consumption. If he uses it as a capital, he employs it in the maintenance of productive labourers, who reproduce the value with a profit. He can, in this case, both restore the capital and pay the interest without alienating or encroaching upon any other source of revenue. If he uses it as a stock reserved for immediate consumption, he acts the part of a prodigal, and dissipates in the maintenance of the idle what was destined for the support of the industrious. He can, in this case, neither restore the capital nor pay the interest without either alienating or encroaching upon some other source of revenue, such as the property or the rent of land."
   The stock which is lent at interest is, no doubt, occasionally employed in both these ways, but in the former much more frequently than in the latter."
  
  
   Book III: Of the different Progress of Opulence in different Nation
  
  Of the Natural Progress of Opulence:
  
   "The great commerce of every civilized society is that carried on between the inhabitants of the town and those of the country. It consists in the exchange of crude for manufactured produce, either immediately, or by the intervention of money, or of some sort of paper which represents money. The country supplies the town with the means of subsistence and the materials of manufacture. The town repays this supply by sending back a part of the manufactured produce to the inhabitants of the country. The town, in which there neither is nor can be any reproduction of substances, may very properly be said to gain its whole wealth and subsistence from the country. We must not, however, upon this account, imagine that the gain of the town is the loss of the country. The gains of both are mutual and reciprocal, and the division of labour is in this, as in all other cases, advantageous to all the different persons employed in the various occupations into which it is subdivided."
  
  Of the Discouragement of Agriculture...: Chapter 2's long title is "Of the Discouragement of Agriculture in the Ancient State of Europe after the Fall of the Roman Empire".
  
   "When the German and Scythian nations overran the western provinces of the Roman empire, the confusions which followed so great a revolution lasted for several centuries. The rapine and violence which the barbarians exercised against the ancient inhabitants interrupted the commerce between the towns and the country. The towns were deserted, and the country was left uncultivated, and the western provinces of Europe, which had enjoyed a considerable degree of opulence under the Roman empire, sunk into the lowest state of poverty and barbarism. During the continuance of those confusions, the chiefs and principal leaders of those nations acquired or usurped to themselves the greater part of the lands of those countries. A great part of them was uncultivated; but no part of them, whether cultivated or uncultivated, was left without a proprietor. All of them were engrossed, and the greater part by a few great proprietors.
   This original engrossing of uncultivated lands, though a great, might have been but a transitory evil. They might soon have been divided again, and broke into small parcels either by succession or by alienation. The law of primogeniture hindered them from being divided by succession: the introduction of entails prevented their being broke into small parcels by alienation."
  
  Of the Rise and Progress of Cities and Towns, after the Fall of the Roman Empire:
  
   "The inhabitants of cities and towns were, after the fall of the Roman empire, not more favoured than those of the country. They consisted, indeed, of a very different order of people from the first inhabitants of the ancient republics of Greece and Italy. These last were composed chiefly of the proprietors of lands, among whom the public territory was originally divided, and who found it convenient to build their houses in the neighbourhood of one another, and to surround them with a wall, for the sake of common defence. After the fall of the Roman empire, on the contrary, the proprietors of land seem generally to have lived in fortified castles on their own estates, and in the midst of their own tenants and dependants. The towns were chiefly inhabited by tradesmen and mechanics, who seem in those days to have been of servile, or very nearly of servile condition. The privileges which we find granted by ancient charters to the inhabitants of some of the principal towns in Europe sufficiently show what they were before those grants. The people to whom it is granted as a privilege that they might give away their own daughters in marriage without the consent of their lord, that upon their death their own children, and not their lord, should succeed to their goods, and that they might dispose of their own effects by will, must, before those grants, have been either altogether or very nearly in the same state of villanage with the occupiers of land in the country."
  
  How the Commerce of the Towns Contributed to the Improvement of the Country: Smith often harshly criticised those who act purely out of self-interest and greed, and warns that,
  
   "...[a]ll for ourselves, and nothing for other people, seems, in every age of the world, to have been the vile maxim of the masters of mankind." (Book 3, Chapter 4)
  
  
   Book IV: Of Systems of political Economy
  
  Smith vigorously attacked the antiquated government restrictions he thought hindered industrial expansion. In fact, he attacked most forms of government interference in the economic process, including tariffs, arguing that this creates inefficiency and high prices in the long run. It is believed that this theory influenced government legislation in later years, especially during the 19th century.
  
  However, this was not an anarchistic opposition to government. Smith advocated a Government that was active in sectors other than the economy. He advocated public education for poor adults, a judiciary, and a standing army—institutional systems not directly profitable for private industries.
  
  Of the Principle of the Commercial or Mercantile System: The book has sometimes been described as a critique of mercantilism and a synthesis of the emerging economic thinking of Smith's time. Specifically, The Wealth of Nations attacks, inter alia, two major tenets of mercantilism:
  
   1. The idea that protectionist tariffs serve the economic interests of a nation (or indeed any purpose whatsoever) and
   2. The idea that large reserves of gold bullion or other precious metals are necessary for a country's economic success. This critique of mercantilism was later used by David Ricardo when he laid out his Theory of Comparative Advantage.
  
  Of Restraints upon the Importation...: Chapter 2's full title is "Of Restraints upon the Importation from Foreign Countries of such Goods as can be Produced at Home". The "Invisible Hand" is a frequently referenced theme from the book, although it is specifically mentioned only once.
  
   "As every individual, therefore, endeavors as much as he can both to employ his capital in the support of domestic industry, and so to direct that industry that its produce may be of the greatest value; every individual necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it." (Book 4, Chapter 2)
  
  Of the extraordinary Restraints...: Chapter 3's long title is "Of the extraordinary Restraints upon the Importation of Goods of almost all Kinds, from those Countries with which the Balance is supposed to be Disadvantageous".
  
  Of Drawbacks: Merchants and manufacturers are not contented with the monopoly of the home market, but desire likewise the most extensive foreign sale for their goods. Their country has no jurisdiction in foreign nations, and therefore can seldom procure them any monopoly there. They are generally obliged, therefore, to content themselves with petitioning for certain encouragements to exportation.
  
  Of these encouragements what are called Drawbacks seem to be the most reasonable. To allow the merchant to draw back upon exportation, either the whole or a part of whatever excise or inland duty is imposed upon domestic industry, can never occasion the exportation of a greater quantity of goods than what would have been exported had no duty been imposed. Such encouragements do not tend to turn towards any particular employment a greater share of the capital of the country than what would go to that employment of its own accord, but only to hinder the duty from driving away any part of that shares to other employments.
  
  Of Bounties: Bounties upon exportation are, in Great Britain, frequently petitioned for, and sometimes granted to the produce of particular branches of domestic industry. By means of them our merchants and manufacturers, it is pretended, will be enabled to sell their goods as cheap, or cheaper than their rivals in the foreign market. A greater quantity, it is said, will thus be exported, and the balance of trade consequently turned more in favour of our own country. We cannot give our workmen a monopoly in the foreign as we have done in the home market. We cannot force foreigners to buy their goods as we have done our own countrymen. The next best expedient, it has been thought, therefore, is to pay them for buying. It is in this manner that the mercantile system proposes to enrich the whole country, and to put money into all our pockets by means of the balance of trade
  
  Of Treaties of Commerce:
  
   "When a nation binds itself by treaty either to permit the entry of certain goods from one foreign country which it prohibits from all others, or to exempt the goods of one country from duties to which it subjects those of all others, the country, or at least the merchants and manufacturers of the country, whose commerce is so favoured, must necessarily derive great advantage from the treaty. Those merchants and manufacturers enjoy a sort of monopoly in the country which is so indulgent to them. That country becomes a market both more extensive and more advantageous for their goods: more extensive, because the goods of other nations being either excluded or subjected to heavier duties, it takes off a greater quantity of theirs: more advantageous, because the merchants of the favoured country, enjoying a sort of monopoly there, will often sell their goods for a better price than if exposed to the free competition of all other nations."
   Such treaties, however, though they may be advantageous to the merchants and manufacturers of the favoured, are necessarily disadvantageous to those of the favouring country. A monopoly is thus granted against them to a foreign nation; and they must frequently buy the foreign goods they have occasion for dearer than if the free competition of other nations was admitted.
  
  Of Colonies:
  
  Of the Motives for establishing new Colonies:
  
   "The interest which occasioned the first settlement of the different European colonies in America and the West Indies was not altogether so plain and distinct as that which directed the establishment of those of ancient Greece and Rome.
   All the different states of ancient Greece possessed, each of them, but a very small territory, and when the people in any one of them multiplied beyond what that territory could easily maintain, a part of them were sent in quest of a new habitation in some remote and distant part of the world; warlike neighbours surrounded them on all sides, rendering it difficult for any of them to enlarge their territory at home. The colonies of the Dorians resorted chiefly to Italy and Sicily, which, in the times preceding the foundation of Rome, were inhabited by barbarous and uncivilised nations: those of the Ionians and Eolians, the two other great tribes of the Greeks, to Asia Minor and the islands of the Egean Sea, of which the inhabitants seem at that time to have been pretty much in the same state as those of Sicily and Italy. The mother city, though she considered the colony as a child, at all times entitled to great favour and assistance, and owing in return much gratitude and respect, yet considered it as an emancipated child over whom she pretended to claim no direct authority or jurisdiction. The colony settled its own form of government, enacted its own laws, elected its own magistrates, and made peace or war with its neighbours as an independent state, which had no occasion to wait for the approbation or consent of the mother city. Nothing can be more plain and distinct than the interest which directed every such establishment."
  
  Causes of Prosperity of new Colonies:
  
   "The colony of a civilised nation which takes possession either of a waste country, or of one so thinly inhabited that the natives easily give place to the new settlers, advances more rapidly to wealth and greatness than any other human society.
   The colonists carry out with them a knowledge of agriculture and of other useful arts superior to what can grow up of its own accord in the course of many centuries among savage and barbarous nations. They carry out with them, too, the habit of subordination, some notion of the regular government which takes place in their own country, of the system of laws which supports it, and of a regular administration of justice; and they naturally establish something of the same kind in the new settlement."
  
  Of the Advantages which Europe has derived from the Discovery of America, and from that of a Passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good Hope:
  
   "Such are the advantages which the colonies of America have derived from the policy of Europe. What are those which Europe has derived from the discovery and colonization of America? Those advantages may be divided, first, into the general advantages which Europe, considered as one great country, has derived from those great events; and, secondly, into the particular advantages which each colonizing country has derived from the colonies which particularly belong to it, in consequence of the authority or dominion which it exercises over them.:
   The general advantages which Europe, considered as one great country, has derived from the discovery and colonization of America, consist, first, in the increase of its enjoyments; and, secondly, in the augmentation of its industry.
   The surplus produce of America, imported into Europe, furnishes the inhabitants of this great continent with a variety of commodities which they could not otherwise have possessed; some for conveniency and use, some for pleasure, and some for ornament, and thereby contributes to increase their enjoyments."
  
  Conclusion of the Mercantile System: Smith's argument about the international political economy opposed the idea of Mercantilism. While the Mercantile System encouraged each country to hoard gold, while trying to grasp hegemony, Smith argued that free trade eventually makes all actors better off. This argument is the modern 'Free Trade' argument.
  
  Of the Agricultural Systems...: Chapter 9's long title is "Of the Agricultural Systems, or of those Systems of Political Economy, which Represent the Produce of Land, as either the Sole or the Principal, Source of the Revenue and Wealth of Every Country".
  
   "That system which represents the produce of land as the sole source of the revenue and wealth of every country has, so far as by that time, never been adopted by any nation, and it at present exists only in the speculations of a few men of great learning and ingenuity in France. It would not, surely, be worthwhile to examine at great length the errors of a system which never has done, and probably never will do, any harm in any part of the world."
  
  
   Book V: Of the Revenue of the Sovereign or Commonwealth
  
  Smith postulated four "maxims" of taxation: proportionality, transparency, convenience, and efficiency. Some economists interpret Smith's opposition to taxes on transfers of money, such as the Stamp Act, as opposition to capital gains taxes, which did not exist in the 18th century. Other economists credit Smith as one of the first to advocate a progressive tax. Smith wrote, "It is not very unreasonable that the rich should contribute to the public expense, not only in proportion to their revenue, but something more in proportion."
  
  Of the Expenses of the Sovereign or Commonwealth: Smith uses this chapter to comment on the concept of taxation and expenditure by the state. On taxation Smith wrote,
  
   "The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state. The expense of government to the individuals of a great nation is like the expense of management to the joint tenants of a great estate, who are all obliged to contribute in proportion to their respective interests in the estate. In the observation or neglect of this maxim consists what is called the equality or inequality of taxation."
  
  Smith advocates a tax naturally attached to the "abilities" and habits of each echelon of society.
  
  For the lower echelon, Smith recognized the intellectually erosive effect that the otherwise beneficial division of labour can have on workers, what Marx, though he mainly opposes Smith, later named "alienation,"; therefore, Smith warns of the consequence of government failing to fulfill its proper role, which is to preserve against the innate tendency of human society to fall apart.
  
   ..."the understandings of the greater part of men are necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose whole life is spent in performing a few simple operations, of which the effects are perhaps always the same, or very nearly the same, has no occasion to exert his understanding or to exercise his invention in finding out expedients for removing difficulties which never occur. He naturally loses, therefore, the habit of such exertion, and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become. The torpor of his mind renders him not only incapable of relishing or bearing a part in any rational conversation, but of conceiving any generous, noble, or tender sentiment, and consequently of forming any just judgment concerning many even of the ordinary duties of private life... But in every improved and civilized society this is the state into which the laboring poor, that is, the great body of the people, must necessarily fall, unless government takes some pains to prevent it."
  
  Under Smith's model, government involvement in any area other than those stated above negatively impacts economic growth. This is because economic growth is determined by the needs of a free market and the entrepreneurial nature of private persons. A shortage of a product makes its price rise, and so stimulates producers to produce more and attracts new people to that line of production. An excess supply of a product (more of the product than people are willing to buy) drives prices down, and producers refocus energy and money to other areas where there is a need.
  
  Of the Sources of the General or Public Revenue of the Society: In his discussion of taxes in Book Five, Smith wrote:
  
   "The necessaries of life occasion the great expense of the poor. They find it difficult to get food, and the greater part of their little revenue is spent in getting it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion the principal expense of the rich, and a magnificent house embellishes and sets off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and vanities which they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore, would in general fall heaviest upon the rich; and in this sort of inequality there would not, perhaps, be anything very unreasonable. It is not very unreasonable that the rich should contribute to the public expense, not only in proportion to their revenue, but something more than in that proportion."
  
   Proponents of progressive taxation cite Smith
   to justify the modern implementation of this idea, the disproportionate taxation of income.
  
  Of War and Public Debts:
  
   "...when war comes [politicians] are both unwilling and unable to increase their [tax] revenue in proportion to the increase of their expense. They are unwilling for fear of offending the people, who, by so great and so sudden an increase of taxes, would soon be disgusted with the war... The facility of borrowing delivers them from the embarrassment... By means of borrowing they are enabled, with a very moderate increase of taxes, to raise, from year to year, money sufficient for carrying on the war, and by the practice of perpetually funding they are enabled, with the smallest possible increase of taxes [to pay the interest on the debt], to raise annually the largest possible sum of money [to fund the war].
  
   ...The return of peace, indeed, seldom relieves them from the greater part of the taxes imposed during the war. These are mortgaged for the interest of the debt contracted in order to carry it on."
  
  Smith then goes on to say that even if money was set aside from future revenues to pay for the debts of war, it seldom actually gets used to pay down the debt. Politicians are inclined to spend the money on some other scheme that will win the favor of their constituents. Hence, interest payments rise and war debts continue to grow larger, well beyond the end of the war.
  
  Summing up, if governments can borrow without check, then they are more likely to wage war without check, and the costs of the war spending will burden future generations, since war debts are almost never repaid by the generations that incurred them.
  
   Reception and impact
  
  The first edition of the book sold out in six months. The printer William Strahan wrote on 12 April 1776 that David Hume had said that The Wealth of Nations required too much thought to be as popular as Edward Gibbon's The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire. Strahan also wrote: "What you say of Mr. Gibbon's and Dr. Smith's book is exactly just. The former is the most popular work; but the sale of the latter, though not near so rapid, has been more than I could have expected from a work that requires much thought and reflection (qualities that do not abound among modern readers) to peruse to any purpose". Gibbon wrote to Adam Ferguson on 1 April: "What an excellent work is that with which our common friend Mr. Adam Smith has enriched the public! An extensive science in a single book, and the most profound ideas expressed in the most perspicuous language". The review of the book in the Annual Register was probably written by Whig MP Edmund Burke.
  
  Smith's biographer John Rae contends that The Wealth of Nations shaped government policy soon after it was published. In 1777 the Prime Minister, Lord North, in the first budget after the book was published, got the idea for two new taxes from the book: one on man-servants and the other on property sold at auction. The budget of 1778 introduced the inhabited house duty and the malt tax, both recommended by Smith. In 1779 Smith was consulted by politicians Henry Dundas and Lord Carlisle on the subject of giving Ireland free trade.
  
  The Wealth of Nations was first mentioned in Parliament by the Whig leader Charles James Fox on 11 November 1783: "There was a maxim laid down in an excellent book upon the Wealth of Nations which had been ridiculed for its simplicity, but which was indisputable as to its truth. In that book it was stated that the only way to become rich was to manage matters so as to make one's income exceed one's expenses. This maxim applied equally to an individual and to a nation. The proper line of conduct therefore was by a well-directed economy to retrench every current expense, and to make as large a saving during the peace as possible". However Fox once told Charles Butler sometime after 1785 that he had never read the book and that "There is something in all these subjects which passes my comprehension; something so wide that I could never embrace them myself nor find any one who did". In 1796 when Fox was dining with Lord Lauderdale, Lauderdale remarked that we knew nothing of political economy before Adam Smith wrote. "Pooh," replied Fox, "your Adam Smiths are nothing, but" (he added, turning to the company) "that is his love; we must spare him there". Lauderdale replied: "I think he is everything", to which Fox rejoined: "That is a great proof of your affection". Fox also found Adam Smith "tedious" and believed that one half of The Wealth of Nations could be "omitted with much benefit to the subject".
  
  In an editorial of The Times on 3 August 1787, it was stated: "It is astonishing to consider, how few merchants are acquainted with Smith's Wealth of Nations, or Anderson's History of Commerce, which are certainly books that should be perused by every man who makes trade his pursuit".
  
  The Wealth of Nations was next mentioned in Parliament by Robert Thornton MP in 1787 to support the Commercial Treaty with France. In the same year George Dempster MP referenced it in the debate on the proposal to farm the post-horse duties and in 1788 by a Mr. Hussy on the Wool Exportation Bill. In 1791 the English radical Thomas Paine wrote in his Rights of Man that "Had Mr. Burke possessed talents similar to the author ‘On the Wealth of Nations,’ he would have comprehended all the parts which enter into, and, by assemblage, form a constitution". The Prime Minister, William Pitt, praised Smith in the House of Commons on 17 February 1792: "...an author of our own times now unfortunately no more (I mean the author of a celebrated treatise on the Wealth of Nations), whose extensive knowledge of detail, and depth of philosophical research will, I believe, furnish the best solution to every question connected with the history of commerce, or with the systems of political economy". In the same year it was quoted by Samuel Whitbread MP and Fox (on the division of labour) in the debate on the armament against Russia and also by William Wilberforce in introducing his Bill against the slave trade. It was not mentioned in the House of Lords until 1793, by Lord Lansdowne and Lord Loughbourough. Lansdowne said: "With respect to French principles, as they had been denominated, those principles had been exported from us to France, and could not be said to have originated among the population of the latter country. The new principles of government founded on the abolition of the old feudal system were originally propagated among us by the Dean of Gloucester, Mr. Tucker, and had since been more generally inculcated by Dr. Smith in his work on the Wealth of Nations, which had been recommended as a book necessary for the information of youth by Mr. Dugald Stewart in his Elements of the Philosophy of the Human Mind". Loughborough replied that "in the works of Dean Tucker, Adam Smith, and Mr. Stewart, to which allusion had been made, no doctrines inimical to the principles of civil government, the morals or religion of mankind, were contained, and therefore to trace the errors of the French to these causes was manifestly fallacious". On 16 May 1797 Pitt said in the debate on the suspension of cash payments by the Bank of England that Smith was "that great author" but his arguments "though always ingenious" were "sometimes injudicious".
  
  Sir John Mitford, the Solicitor-General, said on 22 December 1798 in speaking on cross-bills (a bill of exchange given in consideration of another bill) that Smith "in his Wealth of Nations, explains the nature and pernicious consequences of this practice with his usual perspicuity and philosophical accuracy". On 5 December 1800 Lord Warwick said in a debate on the price of corn that:
  
   There was hardly any kind of property on which the law did not impose some restraints and regulations with regard to the sale of them, except that of provisions. This was probably done on the principles laid down by a celebrated and able writer, Doctor Adam Smith, who had maintained that every thing ought to be left to its own level. He knew something of that Gentleman, whose heart he knew was as sound as his head; and he was sure that had he lived to this day and beheld the novel state of wretchedness to which the country was now reduced—a state, which as the like had never occurred before, could never have entered into his mind; that Great Man would have reason to blush for some of the doctrines he had laid down. He would now have abundant opportunities of observing that all those artificial means of enhancing the price of provisions, which he had considered as no way mischievous, were practised at this time to a most alarming extent. He would see the Farmer keeping up his produce while the poor were labouring under all the miseries of want, and he would see Forestallers, Regraters, and all kinds of Middle-men making large profits upon it.
  
  Lord Grenville replied that "he must remind him, that so far from there having been any difference in the state of the Country when that great man lived, and the present times, his book was first published at a period, previous to which there had been two or three seasons of great dearth and distress; and during those seasons there were speculators without number, who raised an unfounded and unjust clamour against Forestallers and Regraters, and who proposed that a certain price should be fixed on every article: but all their plans were wisely rejected, and the Treatise on the Wealth of Nations, which came forward soon after, pointed out in the clearest light how absurd and futile they must have been".
  
  In 1800 the Anti-Jacobin Review criticised The Wealth of Nations and Robert Southey in 1812 in the Quarterly Review condemned The Wealth of Nations as a "tedious and hard-hearted book".
  
  In 1803 The Times argued against war with Spain: "She is our best customer; and by the gentle and peaceable stream of commerce, the treasures of the new world flow with greater certainty into English reservoirs, than it could do by the most successful warfare. They come in this way to support our manufactures, to encourage industry, to feed our poor, to pay taxes, to reward ingenuity, to diffuse riches among all classes of people. But for the full understanding of this beneficial circulation of wealth, we must refer to Dr. Adam Smith's incomparable Treatise on the Wealth of Nations". In 1810 a correspondent writing under the pseudonym of Publicola included at the head of his letter Smith's line that "Exclusive Companies are nuisances in every respect" and called him "that learned writer". In 1821 The Times quoted Smith's opinion that the interests of corn dealers and the people were the same.
  
  In 1826 the English radical William Cobbett criticised in his Rural Rides the political economists' hostility to the Poor Law: "Well, amidst all this suffering, there is one good thing; the Scotch political economy is blown to the devil, and the Edinburgh Review and Adam Smith along with it".
  
  The Radical MP Richard Cobden as a young man studied The Wealth of Nations; his copy is still in the library of his home at Dunford House and there are lively marginal notes on the places where Smith condemns British colonial policy. There are none on the passage about the invisible hand. Cobden campaigned for free trade in his agitation against the Corn Laws. On 13 October 1843 Cobden quoted (accurately) Smith's protest against the "plain violation of the most sacred property" of every man derived from his labour. On 8 May 1844 he cited Smith's opposition to slave labour and on 3 July 1844 claimed that Smith had been misrepresentated by protectionists as a monopolist. On 8 October 1849 Cobden claimed that he had "gone through the length and breadth of this country, with Adam Smith in my hand, to advocate the principles of Free Trade." He also said he had tried "to popularise to the people of this country, and of the Continent, those arguments with which Adam Smith, David Hume, Ricardo, and every man who has written on this subject, have demonstrated the funding system to be injurious to mankind, and unjust in principle". Cobden believed it to be morally wrong to lend money to be spent on war. When The Times claimed the political economists were against Cobden on this, Cobden wrote on 16 October 1849: "I can quote Adam Smith whose authority is without appeal now in intellectual circles, it gives one the basis of science upon which to raise appeals to the moral feelings". When in 1850 the Russian government attempted to raise a loan, ostensibly for the construction of a railway from St. Petersburg to Moscow, but actually to cover the deficit brought about by its war against Hungary, Cobden said on 18 January: "I take my stand on one of the strongest grounds in stating that Adam Smith and other great authorities on political economy are opposed to the very principle of such loans". In 1863, during Cobden's dispute with The Times over its claims that his fellow Radical John Bright wanted to divide the land of the rich amongst the poor, Cobden read to a friend the passage in the Wealth of Nations which criticised primogeniture and entail. Cobden said that if Bright had been as plain-speaking as Smith, "how he would have been branded as an incendiary and Socialist". On 23 November 1864 Cobden proclaimed: "If I were five-and-twenty or thirty, instead of, unhappily, twice that number of years, I would take Adam Smith in hand—I would not go beyond him, I would have no politics in it—I would take Adam Smith in hand, and I would have a League for free trade in Land just as we had a League for free trade in Corn. You will find just the same authority in Adam Smith for the one as for the other; and if it were only taken up as it must be taken up to succeed, not as a political, revolutionary, Radical, Chartist notion, but taken up on politico-economic grounds, the agitation would be certain to succeed".
  
  The Liberal statesman William Ewart Gladstone chaired the meeting of the Political Economy Club to celebrate the centenary of the publication of The Wealth of Nations.
  
  The Liberal historian Lord Acton believed that The Wealth of Nations gave a "scientific backbone to liberal sentiment" and that it was the "classic English philosophy of history".
  
   United State
  
  James Madison, in a speech given in Congress on 2 February 1791, cited The Wealth of Nations in opposing a national bank: "The principal disadvantages consisted in, 1st. banishing the precious metals, by substituting another medium to perform their office: This effect was inevitable. It was admitted by the most enlightened patrons of banks, particularly by Smith on the Wealth of Nations". Thomas Jefferson, writing to John Norvell on 14 June 1807, claimed that on "the subjects of money & commerce, Smith's Wealth of Nations is the best book to be read, unless Say's Political Economy can be had, which treats the same subject on the same principles, but in a shorter compass & more lucid manner".
  
   Two views of the "Wealth of Nations"
  
  In the Preface to his edition, Cannan shows that of the major part of the "Wealth of Nations" follows Adam Smith’s earlier lectures, but that there are important additions due to his visit to France. These additions were so important for Smith that he puts them at the beginning of his work. For Cannan as a neoclassic economist they are superfluous and not the real Adam Smith: "These changes do not make so much real difference to Smith’s own work as might be supposed; the theory of distribution, though it appears in the title of Book I., is no essential part of the work and could easily be excised … But to subsequent [classical] economics they were of fundamental importance. They settled the form of economic treatises for a century at least."
  
  The "Wealth of Nations" is therefore inhomogeneous and consists of the earlier elements of an individualistic strain in the tradition of Aristotle, Puffendorf and Hutcheson, Smith’s teacher, – elements compatible with a neoclassical theory – and the classical theory Smith learned in France.
  
  Smith’s classical message is what he states at the very beginning: the two ways to create the “Wealth of Nations”. First, make productive labour even more productive by enhancing markets to deepen the division of labour (moving the neoclassical production curve to the right); and second, use more labour productively instead of unproductively, i.e., produce more goods and services that are inputs to the next economic reproduction circle, as opposed to goods used up in final consumption. In the words of Adam Smith:
  
   "The annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally supplies it with all the necessaries and conveniences of life which it annually consumes … . [T]his produce … bears a greater or smaller proportion to the number of those who are to consume it … .[B]ut this proportion must in every nation be regulated by two different circumstances;
  
   * first, by the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which its labour is generally applied; and,
   * secondly, by the proportion between the number of those who are employed in useful labour, and that of those who are not so employed [emphasis added]."
  
  Ricardo repeats this in identical terms. Smith’s and the classical macro-economical distinction between productive and unproductive labour gives no sense within neoclassical micro-economics as any labour or idleness of a homo oeconomicus maximises his micro-economic “utility” and is therefore productive.
  
  For neoclassical economists Smith’s central message is the Invisible hand mentioned deep in the books and seen as a proto-neoclassical statement of the neoclassical General equilibrium theory:
  
   "[E]very individual necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain; and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.”
  
  This often quoted passage describes the unintentional consequences that come from individuals' pursuit of their "own gain" and security. Smith argued people prefer local industry and are biased against international trade. Ideally, he saw economics as characterized by small local economies interacting with each other and guided by the enlightened self-interest of individuals. This was a reaction against the practices of early transnational corporations (for example: the British East India Company and Muscovy Company), which were mostly unresponsive to local affairs and stewardship of resources. Though the argument is frequently, and incorrectly, used to justify free-trade policies, The Wealth of Nations was a rebuttal to the scale and effects of chartered monopoly. By positing—now famously—that "self-interest" promotes more just societies, he was prescribing to economies already heavily tilted against individual human agency. For instance, American colonists were permitted to grow cotton but not to manufacture with it. They had to sell cotton to England for processing, then buy it back as clothing. Smith felt opposing large multinational corporations (and the governments that support them), allowed individuals to direct industry "in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value." This value comes from the individual's self-interest and leads to a result that is "no part of his intention."
  
  
   Contemporary evaluation
  
  George Stigler attributes to Smith "the most important substantive proposition in all of economics" and foundation of resource-allocation theory. It is that, under competition, owners of resources (labor, land, and capital) will use them most profitably, resulting in an equal rate of return in equilibrium for all uses (adjusted for apparent differences arising from such factors as training, trust, hardship, and unemployment). He also describes Smith's theorem that "the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market" as the "core of a theory of the functions of firm and industry" and a "fundamental principle of economic organization."
  
  Paul Samuelson finds in Smith's pluralist use of supply and demand—as applied to wages, rents, and profit—a valid and valuable anticipation of the general equilibrium modeling of Walras a century later. Moreover, Smith's allowance for wage increases in the short and intermediate term from capital accumulation and invention added a realism missed later by Malthus, Ricardo, and Marx in their propounding a rigid subsistence-wage theory of labour supply.
  
  Mark Blaug argues that it was Smith's achievement to shift the burden of proof against those maintaining that the pursuit of self-interest does not achieve social good. But he notes Smith's relevant attention to definite institutional arrangements and process as disciplining self-interest to widen the scope of the market, accumulate capital, and grow income.
序論及全書設計
  一國國民每年的勞動,本來就是供給他們每年消費的一切生活必需品和便利品的源
  泉。構成這種必需品和便利品的,或是本國勞動的直接産物,或是用這類産物從外國購
  進來的物品。
  這類産物或用這類産物從外國購進來的物品,對消費者人數,或是有着大的比例,
  或是有着小的比例,所以一國國民所需要的一切必需品和便利品供給情況的好壞,視這
  一比例的大小而定。
  但無論就哪一國國民說,這一比例都要受下述兩種情況的支配:第一,一般地說,
  這一國國民運用勞動,是怎樣熟練,怎樣技巧,怎樣有判斷力;第二,從事有用勞動的
  人數和不從事有用勞動的人數,究成什麽比例。不論一國土壤、氣候和面積是怎樣,它
  的國民每年供給的好壞,必然取决於這兩種情況。
  此外,上述供給的好壞,取决於前一情況的,似乎較多。在未開化的漁獵民族間,
  一切能夠勞作的人都或多或少地從事有用勞動,盡可能以各種生活必需品和便利品,供
  給他自己和傢內族內因老幼病弱而不能漁獵的人。不過,他們是那麽貧乏,以致往往僅
  因為貧乏的緣故,迫不得已,或至少覺得迫不得已,要殺害老幼以及長期患病的親人;
  或遺棄這些人,聽其餓死或被野獸吞食。反之,在文明繁榮的民族間,雖有許多人全然
  不從事勞動,而且他們所消費的勞動生産物,往往比大多數勞動者所消費的要多過十倍
  乃至百倍。但由於社會全部勞動生産物非常之多,往往一切人都有充足的供給,就連最
  下等最貧窮的勞動者,衹要勤勉節儉,也比野蠻人享受更多的生活必需品和便利品。
  勞動生産力的這種改良的原因,究竟在那裏,勞動的生産物,按照什麽順序自然而
  然地分配給社會上各階級?這就是本書第一篇的主題。
  在勞動運用上已有相當程度的熟練、技巧和判斷力的不同國民,對於勞動的一般管
  理或指導,曾采取極不相同的計劃。這些計劃,並不同等地有利於一國生産物的增加。
  有些國傢的政策,特別鼓勵農村的産業;另一些國傢的政策,卻特別鼓勵城市的産業。
  對於各種産業,不偏不倚地使其平均發展的國傢,怕還沒有。自羅馬帝國崩潰以來,歐
  洲各國的政策,都比較不利於農村的産業,即農業,而比較有利於城市的産業,即工藝、
  製造業和商業。本書第三篇將說明,什麽情況使人們采用和規定這種政策。這些計劃的
  實行,最初也許是起因於特殊階級的利益與偏見,對於這些計劃將如何影響社會全體的
  福利,他們不曾具有遠見,亦不曾加以考慮。可是,這些計劃卻引起了極不相同的經濟
  學說。有的人認為城市産業重要;有的人又力說農村産業重要。這些不相同的學說,不
  僅對學者們的意見産生了相當大的影響,而且君王和國傢的政策亦為它們所左右。我將
  盡我所能,在本書第四篇詳細明確地解釋這些不同學說,並說明它們在各時代和各國中
  所産生的重要影響。
  要之,本書前四篇的目的,在於說明廣大人民的收入是怎樣構成的,並說明供應各
  時代各國民每年消費的資源,究竟有什麽性質。第五篇即最後一篇所討論的,是君主或
  國傢的收入。在這一篇裏,我要努力說明以下各點:第一,什麽是君主或國傢的必要費
  用,其中,哪些部分應該出自由全社會負擔的賦稅,哪些部分應該出自社會某特殊階級
  或成員負擔的特殊賦稅。第二,來自全社會所有納稅人的經費是怎樣募集的,而各種募
  集方法大抵有什麽利弊。第三,什麽使幾乎所有近代各國政府都把收入的一部分,作為
  擔保來舉債,而這種債務,對於真實財富,換言之,對於社會的土地和勞動的年産物,
  有什麽影響。
第一章 論分工
  勞動生産力上最大的增進,以及運用勞動時所表現的更大的熟練、技巧和判斷力,
  似乎都是分工的結果。
  為使讀者易於理解社會一般業務分工所産生的結果,我現在來討論個別製造業分工
  狀況。一般人認為,分工最完全的製造業,乃是一些極不重要的製造業。不重要製造業
  的分工,實際上並不比重要製造業的分工更為周密。但是,目的在於供給少數人小量需
  要的不重要製造業,所雇用的勞動者人數,必然不多,而從事各部門工作的工人,往往
  可集合在同一工廠內,使觀察者能一覽無遺。反之,那些大製造業,要供給大多數人的
  大量需要,所以,各工作部門都雇有許許多多勞動者,要把這許許多多勞動者集合在一
  個廠內,勢不可能。我們要同時看見一個部門以上的工人,也不可能。象這種大製造業
  的工作,儘管實際上比小製造業分成多得多的部分,但因為這種劃分不能象小製造業的
  劃分那麽明顯,所以很少人註意到。
  扣針製造業是極微小的了,但它的分工往往喚起人們的註意。所以,我把它引來作
  為例子。一個勞動者,如果對於這職業(分工的結果,使扣針的製造成為一種專門職業)
  沒有受過相當訓練,又不知怎樣使用這職業上的機械(使這種機械有發明的可能的,恐
  怕也是分工的結果),那末縱使竭力工作,也許一天也製造不出一枚扣針,要做二十枚,
  當然是决不可能了。但按照現在經營的方法,不但這種作業全部已經成為專門職業,而
  且這種職業分成若幹部門,其中有大多數也同樣成為專門職業。一個人抽鐵綫,一個人
  拉直,一個人切截,一個人削尖綫的一端,一個人磨另一端,以便裝上圓頭。要做圓頭,
  就需要有二三種不同的操作。裝圓頭,塗白色,乃至包裝,都是專門的職業。這樣,扣
  針的製造分為十八種操作。有些工廠,這十八種操作,分由十八個專門工人擔任。固然,
  有時一人也兼任二三門。我見過一個這種小工廠,衹雇用十個工人,因此在這一個工廠
  中,有幾個工人擔任二三種操作。象這樣一個小工廠的工人,雖很窮睏,他們的必要機
  械設備,雖很簡陋,但他們如果勤勉努力,一日也能成針十二磅。從每磅中等針有四千
  枚計,這十個工人每日就可成針四萬八千枚,即一人一日可成針四千八百枚。如果他們
  各自獨立工作,不專習一種特殊業務,那末,他們不論是誰,絶對不能一日製造二十枚
  針,說不定一天連一枚針也製造不出來。他們不但不能製出今日由適當分工合作而製成
  的數量的二百四十分之一,就連這數量的四千八百分之一,恐怕也製造不出來。
  就其他各種工藝及製造業說,雖有許多不能作這樣細密的分工,共操作也不能變得
  這樣簡單,但分工的效果總是一樣的。凡能采用分工製的工藝,一經采用分工製,便相
  應地增進勞動的生産力。各種行業之所以各各分立,似乎也是由於分工有這種好處。一
  個國傢的産業與勞動生産力的增進程度如果是極高的,則其各種行業的分工一般也都達
  到極高的程度。未開化社會中一人獨任的工作,在進步的社會中,一般都成為幾個人分
  任的工作。在進步的社會中,農民一般衹是農民,製造者衹是製造者。而且,生産一種
  完全製造品所必要的勞動,也往往分由許多勞動者擔任。試以麻織業和毛織業為例,從
  亞麻及羊毛的生産到麻布的漂白和燙平或呢絨的染色和最後一道加工,各部門所使用的
  不同技藝是那麽多啊!農業由於它的性質,不能有象製造業那樣細密的分工,各種工作,
  不能象製造業那樣判然分立。木匠的職業與鐵匠的職業,通常是截然分開的,但畜牧者
  的業務與種稻者的業務,不能象前者那樣完全分開。紡工和織工,幾乎都是各別的兩個
  人,但鋤耕、耙掘、播種和收割,卻常由一人兼任。農業上種種勞動,隨季節推移而巡
  回,要指定一個人衹從事一種勞動,事實上絶不可能。所以,農業上勞動生産力的增進,
  總跟不上製造業上勞動生産力的增進的主要原因,也許就是農業不能采用完全的分工製
  度。現在最富裕的國傢,固然在農業和製造業上都優於鄰國,但製造業方面的優越程度,
  必定大於農業方面的優越程度。富國的土地,一般都耕耘得較好,投在土地上的勞動與
  費用也比較多,生産出來的産品按照土地面積與肥沃的比例來說也較多;但是,這樣較
  大的生産量,很少在比例上大大超過所花的較大勞動量和費用。在農業方面,富國勞動
  生産力未必都比貧國勞動生産力大得多,至少不象製造業方面一般情況那樣大得多。所
  以,如果品質同樣優良,富國小麥在市場上的售價,未必都比貧國低廉。就富裕和進步
  的程度說,法國遠勝於波蘭,但波蘭小麥的價格,與品質同樣優良的法國小麥同樣低廉。
  與英格蘭比較,論富裕,論進步,法國可能要遜一籌,但法國産麥省出産的小麥,其品
  質之憂良完全和英格蘭小麥相同,而且在大多數年頭,兩者的價格也大致相同。可是,
  英格蘭的麥田耕種得比法國好,而法國的麥田,據說耕種得比波蘭好得多。貧國的耕作,
  儘管不及富國,但貧國生産的小麥,在品質優良及售價低廉方面,卻能在相當程度上與
  富國競爭。但是,貧國在製造業上不能和富國競爭;至少在富國土壤氣候位置適宜於這
  類製造業的場合,貧國不能和富國競爭。法國綢所以比英國綢又好又便宜,就是因為織
  綢業,至少在今日原絲進口稅很高的條件下,更適合於法國氣候,而不十分適合於英國
  氣候。但英國的鐵器和粗毛織物,卻遠勝於法國,而且品質同樣優良的英國貨品,在價
  格上比法國低廉得多。據說,波蘭除了少數立國所需的粗糙家庭製造業外,幾乎沒有什
  麽製造業。
  有了分工,同數勞動者就能完成比過去多得多的工作量,其原因有三:第一,勞動
  者的技巧因業專而日進;第二,由一種工作轉到另一種工作,通常須損失不少時間,有
  了分工,就可以免除這種損失;第三,許多簡化勞動和縮減勞動的機械的發明,使一個
  人能夠做許多人的工作。
  第一,勞動者熟練程度的增進,勢必增加他所能完成的工作量。分工實施的結果,
  各勞動者的業務,既然終生局限於一種單純操作,當然能夠大大增進自己的熟練程度。
  慣於使用鐵錘而不曾練習製鐵釘的普通鐵匠,一旦因特殊事故,必須製釘時,我敢說,
  他一天至多衹能做出二三百枚針來,而且質量還拙劣不堪。即使慣於製釘,但若不以製
  釘為主業或專業,就是竭力工作,也不會一天製造出八百枚或一千枚以上。我看見過幾
  個專以製釘為業的不滿二十歲的青年人,在盡力工作時,每人每日能製造二千三百多枚。
  可是,製釘决不是最簡單的操作。同一勞動者,要鼓爐、調整火力,要燒鐵揮錘打製,
  在打製釘頭時還得調換工具。比較起來,製扣針和製金屬紐扣所需的各項操作要簡單得
  多,而以此為終生業務的人,其熟練程度通常也高得多。所以,在此等製造業中,有幾
  種操作的迅速程度簡直使人難於想象,如果你不曾親眼見過,你决不會相信人的手能有
  這樣大的本領。
  第二,由一種工作轉到另一種工作,常要損失一些時間,因節省這種時間而得到的
  利益,比我們驟看到時所想象的大得多。不可能很快地從一種工作轉到使用完全不相同
  工具而且在不同地方進行的另一種工作。耕作小農地的鄉村織工,由織機轉到耕地,又
  由耕地轉到織機,一定要虛費許多時間。誠然,這兩種技藝,如果能在同一廠坊內進行,
  那末時間上的損失,無疑要少得多,但即使如此,損失還是很大。人由一種工作轉到另
  一種工作時,通常要閑逛一會兒。在開始新工作之初,勢難立即精神貫註地積極工作,
  總不免心不在焉。而且在相當時間內,與其說他是在工作,倒不如說他是在開玩笑。閑
  蕩、偷懶、隨便這種種習慣,對於每半小時要換一次工作和工具,而且一生中幾乎每天
  必須從事二十項不同工作的農村勞動者,可說是自然會養成的,甚而可說必然會養成的。
  這種種習慣,使農村勞動者常流於遲緩懶惰,即在非常吃緊的時候,也不會精神勃勃地
  幹。所以,縱使沒有技巧方面的缺陷,僅僅這些習慣也一定會大大減少他所能完成的工
  作量。
  第三,利用適當的機械能在什麽程度上簡化勞動和節省勞動,這必定是大傢都知道
  的,無須舉例。我在這裏所要說的衹是:簡化勞動和節省勞動的那些機械的發明,看來
  也是起因於分工。人類把註意力集中在單一事物上,比把註意力分散在許多種事物上,
  更能發現達到目標的更簡易更便利的方法。分工的結果,各個人的全部註意力自然會傾
  註在一種簡單事物上。所以衹要工作性質上還有改良的餘地,各個勞動部門所雇的勞動
  者中,不久自會有人發現一些比較容易而便利的方法,來完成他們各自的工作。唯其如
  此,用在今日分工最細密的各種製造業上的機械,有很大部分,原是普通工人的發明。
  他們從事於最單純的操作,當然會發明比較便易的操作方法。不論是誰,衹要他常去觀
  察製造廠,他一定會看到極象樣的機械,這些機械是普通工人為了要使他們擔當的那部
  分工作容易迅速地完成而發明出來的。最初的蒸汽機,原需雇用一個兒童,按活塞的升
  降,不斷開閉汽鍋與汽筒間的通路。有一次擔任這工作的某兒童,因為愛和朋友遊玩,
  他用一條繩把開閉通路的舌門的把手,係在機械的另一部分,舌門就可不需人力自行開
  閉。原為貪玩想出來的方法,就這樣成為蒸汽機大改良之一。
  可是,一切機械的改良,决不是至由機械使用者發明。有許多改良,是出自專門機
  械製造師的智巧;還有一些改良,是出自哲學家或思想傢的智能。哲學家或思想傢的任
  務,不在於製造任何實物,而在於觀察一切事物,所衹他們常常能夠結合利用各種完全
  沒有關係而且極不類似的物力。隨着社會的進步,哲學或推想也象其他各種職業那樣,
  成為某一特定階級人民的主要業務和專門工作。一此外,這種業務或工作,也象其他職
  業那樣,分成了許多部門,每個部門,又各成為一種哲學家的行業。哲學上這種分工,
  象産業上的分工那樣,增進了技巧,並節省了時間。各人擅長各人的特殊工們不但增加
  全體的成就,而且大大增進科學的內容。
  在一個政治修明的社會裏,造成普及到最下層人民的那種普遍富裕情況的,是各行
  各業的産量由於分工而大增。各勞動者,除自身所需數的以外,還有大量産物可以出賣;
  同時,因為一切其他勞動者的處境相同,各個人都能以自身生産的大量産物,換得其他
  勞動着生産的大量産物,換言之,都能換得其他勞動者大量産物的價格。別人所需的物
  品,他能與以充分供給;他自身所需的,別人亦能與以充分供給。於是,社會各階級普
  遍富裕。
  考察一下文明而繁榮的國傢的最普通技工或日工的日用物品罷;你就會看到,用他
  的勞動的一部分(雖然衹是一小部分)來生産這種日用品的人的數目,是難以數計的。
  例如,日工所穿的粗劣呢級上衣,就是許多勞動者聯合勞動的産物。為完成這種樸素的
  産物,勢須有牧羊者、揀羊毛者、梳羊毛者、染工、粗梳工、紡工、織工、漂白工、裁
  縫工,以及其他許多人,聯合起來工作。加之,這些勞動者居住的地方,往往相隔很遠,
  把材料由甲地運至乙地,該需要多少商人和運輸者啊!染工所用藥料,常須購自世界上
  各個遙遠的地方,要把各種藥料由各個不同地方收集起來,該需要多少商業和航運業,
  該需要雇用多少船工、水手、帆布製造者和繩索製造者啊!為生産這些最普通勞動者所
  使用的工具,又需要多少種類的勞動啊!復雜機械如水手工作的船、漂白工用的水車或
  織工用的織機,姑置不論,單就簡單器械如牧羊者剪毛時所用的剪刀來說,其製造就須
  經過許多種類的勞動。為了生産這極簡單的剪刀,礦工、熔鐵爐建造者、木材采伐者、
  熔鐵廠燒炭工人、製磚者、泥水匠、在熔鐵爐旁服務的工人、機械安裝工人、鐵匠等等,
  必須把他們各種各樣的技藝聯結起來。同樣,要是我們考察一個勞動者的服裝和家庭用
  具,如貼身穿的粗麻襯衣,腳上穿的鞋子,就寢用的床鋪和床鋪上各種裝置,調製食物
  的爐子,由地下采掘出來而且也許需要經過水陸運輸才能送到他手邊供他燒飯的煤炭,
  廚房中一切其他用具,食桌上一切用具,刀子和叉子,盛放食物和分取食物的陶製和錫
  蠟製器皿,製造面包和麥酒供他食喝的各種工人,那種透得熱氣和光綫並能遮蔽風雨的
  玻璃窗,和使世界北部成為極舒適的居住地的大發明所必須藉助的一切知識和技術,
  及工人製造這些便利品所用的各種器具等等。總之,我們如果考察這一切東西,並考慮
  到投在這每樣東西上的各種勞動,我們就會覺得,沒有成千上萬的人的幫助和合作,一
  個文明國傢裏的卑不足道的人,即便按照(這是我們很錯誤地想象的)他一般適應的舒
  服簡單的方式也不能夠取得其日用品的供給的。
首頁>> >> 经济商企>> 亞當·斯密 Adam Smith   英國 United Kingdom   漢諾威王朝   (1723年六月5日1790年七月17日)